4474 stories
·
16 followers

prismatic-bell: naamahdarling: atreefullofstars: theunnamedstranger: jumpingjacktrash: xenoqueer:...

2 Shares

prismatic-bell:

naamahdarling:

atreefullofstars:

theunnamedstranger:

jumpingjacktrash:

xenoqueer:

nettlepatchwork:

pervocracy:

Note to vacationing non-Americans: while it’s true that America doesn’t always have the best food culture, the food in our restaurants is really not representative of what most of us eat at home.  The portions at Cheesecake Factory or IHOP are meant to be indulgent, not just “what Americans are used to.”

If you eat at a regular American household, during a regular meal where they’re not going out of their way to impress guests, you probably will not be served twelve pounds of chocolate-covered cream cheese.  Please bear this in mind before writing yet another “omg I can’t believe American food” post.

Also, most American restaurant portions are 100% intended as two meals’ worth of food. Some of my older Irish relatives still struggle with the idea that it’s not just not rude to eat half your meal and take the rest home, it’s expected. (Apparently this is somewhat of an American custom.)

Until you’re hitting the “fancy restaurant” tier (the kind of place you go for a celebration or an anniversary date), a dinner out should generally also be lunch for the next day. Leftovers are very much the norm.

From the little time I’ve spent in Canada, this seems to be the case up there as well.

the portions in family restaurants (as opposed to haute cuisine types) are designed so that no one goes away hungry.

volume IS very much a part of the american hospitality tradition, and Nobody Leaves Hungry is important. but you have to recognize that it’s not how we cook for ourselves, it’s how we welcome guests and strengthen community ties.

so in order to give you a celebratory experience and make you feel welcomed, family restaurants make the portions big enough that even if you’re a teenage boy celebrating a hard win on the basketball court, you’re still going to be comfortably full when you leave.

of course, that means that for your average person with a sit-down job, who ate a decent lunch that day, it’s twice as much as they want or more. that’s ok. as mentioned above, taking home leftovers is absolutely encouraged. that, too, is part of american hospitality tradition; it’s meant to invoke fond memories of grandma loading you down with covered dishes so you can have hearty celebration food all week. pot luck church basement get-togethers where the whole town makes sure everybody has enough. that sort of thing. it’s about sharing. it’s about celebrating Plenty.

it’s not about pigging out until you get huge. treating it that way is pretty disrespectful of our culture. and you know, contrary to what the world thinks, we do have one.

Reblogging because I honestly never thought about it but yeah, this lines up.

This is also why the idea of “pay a lot for fancy food on tiny plates” pisses so many Americans off. Unless you are rich enough not to care about throwing your money away, it’s not just a ridiculous ripoff in terms of not filling you up, it’s stingy. Restaurants are places of hospitality. If I pay that much for a plate it had better be damn good and it had better be generous. Otherwise they are just trying to fleece me out of my money AND saying they don’t value me as a customer.

If I go to IHOP or Olive Garden or whatnot, I absolutely don’t need to eat again until evening if I had leftovers, and until the next day if I did eat everything (you can’t really take pancakes home as leftovers).

But EVEN IF I DID EAT EVERYTHING and then ate a full meal on top of that, later, it’s really not anyone’s place to criticize what other people eat. It just isn’t. Let it go. It’s old.

Making fun of American food culture and food habits isn’t original or surprising or witty or funny or getting one over on us or crafting a clever retort or whatever. It’s lazy and petty and childish.

Yeah, we eat a lot of hamburgers. They’re fucking delicious. Cope.

Also re: Nobody Goes Away Hungry, here is AN INCOMPLETE LIST of things my family was gifted by neighbors when I was a child:

—Nina won a writing contest and xir name was in the newspaper, have a cake

—Nina won a writing contest and xir name was in the newspaper, have some cookies

—Nina won a writing contest and xir name was in the newspaper, have a box of licorice (as you can tell this was Very Big News in my neighborhood)

—it’s Christmas, have cookies

—my garden did really well this year, have zucchini and tomatoes and corn also do you like rhubarb

—we saw an ambulance at your house this morning, have a lasagna

—we heard your mother died, have some soup and a bag of groceries

—Nina looked hungry and nobody is mentioning you’re on food stamps because we’re polite, also we just so happened to cook way too much for dinner, have some chicken

—it’s a block party, everyone take home whatever you want…no, more than that….MORE than that! You think we want to eat all this potato salad by ourselves?!

—we heard your husband had heart surgery, here’s a prepped meal so you can eat properly when you get home from the hospital

—it’s Halloween in a small town, have some apples/popcorn balls/pumpkin bread

—I’m a coupon queen and at the end of this shopping trip the store owed me $10 PLEASE tell me you want groceries I have 42 cans of baked beans

—because why not



I am genuinely bothered by how much this tradition seems to be going by the wayside. This was a whole thing when I was a kid, and there’s literally etiquette for how you handle it:

1) hot meals for tragedy and postpartum assistance, sweets for celebration and introduction.

2) presentation is important—don’t present a burnt or dirty dish. Dishes should have a lid or foil on top. Cling wrap isn’t rude, but it should be avoided because it’s easier to accidentally tear and if it’s not wrapped just right it’ll come undone, which is particularly problematic if you’re leaving food at a doorstep where ants may be present. (1990s addendum: when I was a kid you could buy colored or printed cling wrap around Christmas, and it was considered classy to use this on sweets you were gifting your neighbors as long as it was done in person and wasn’t a doorstep dropoff. This, sadly, seems to have gone away, and I miss it a lot.)

3) when receiving food, always say thank you. Never reject a dish; if it’s food you don’t like, someone in your extended family will take it. If four other people in the neighborhood have already gifted you food and you have no idea what to do with it all, freeze some or gift it to people in your out-of-the-neighborhood circle. The only polite rejections are dietary restrictions, and “three other people have already given me zucchini I’m so sorry.” If all else fails, take it to the break room at work. Someone who forgot their lunch will thank you.

4) Never return a dirty dish.

5) Never return an EMPTY dish. It’s always good to have two or three quick, low-effort recipes in your back pocket for refilling a dish. There is no rule for what you should use as a thank-you recipe, but most people use sweets because there are a lot of quick and simple options and you can refill the dish without cooking in it. (My go-tos are fudge no-bake cookies and honey milk balls. A lot of people in my neighborhood did cookie bars.)

5a) …unless you’re a new parent or the dish was presented to you as a consolation for a funeral. In these cases, a thank-you card will suffice.

6) a dish should always be returned within seven days.

7) using disposable dishes is acceptable, but consider the occasion. A new parent will be grateful for one less dish to wash. Someone who just lost a parent should not be presented with a paper plate.

8) if using disposable dishes, make sure you indicate you don’t expect them back. Some people (I am one of them) will absolutely look at disposable-but-reusable dishes, wash them out, and return them if you do not do this. Never give a disposable dish with the expectation it will return home.

9) if giving a pass-me-on plate/Amish friendship plate, be sure the recipient knows the rules of a pass-me-on plate. You can purchase plates with the rules printed directly on them, but if you’re using a regular plate, gift it with a card that explains the game.



THIS WAS A WHOLE THING. You’ll notice #9 up there—pass-me-on plates are usually somewhere in size between a dinner plate and a serving plate, often very pretty, and the way they work is you fill them up with something good to eat and give them to a friend. The friend will then wash the plate, fill it with something good, and pass it on to someone else—hence the name pass-me-on plate. (The phrase “Amish friendship plate” is….older. With all the slightly wincey connotations of “older” when discussing out-groups.)


This was a way families bonded with other families and cared for our communities, and I really want to see it come back.

Read the whole story
mareino
6 hours ago
reply
Washington, District of Columbia
hannahdraper
6 hours ago
reply
Washington, DC
Share this story
Delete

At Last, Washington Realizes the Obvious Truth About Marijuana

1 Share
It was never among the most dangerous drugs on earth, and the Biden administration is finally doing something about it.
Read the whole story
mareino
20 hours ago
reply
Washington, District of Columbia
Share this story
Delete

The positive case for Joe Biden

1 Share

It’s politics season in America, so I’m going to write a bit about politics.

Trump was doing very well in the polls a few months ago, but Biden has surged lately, and both polls and betting markets now have the candidates essentially even. Back in January, I wrote a post making the case against voting for Trump:

Trump’s chaotic and dictatorial nature, by itself, is easily enough of a reason to cast a vote for Biden in November. But I also think that Biden has been a good President in his own right. So in this post I want to explain why unless something major changes, I plan to vote for Biden, instead of simply against Trump.

I am not a Biden shill

In my post about Trump, I started off with a whole section explaining why I don’t have “Trump derangement syndrome” — in fact, Trump did a number of good things in his first term, and I gave him credit for these. So I want to start this post off with something similar — I want to explain why I’m not a simple knee-jerk Biden supporter who tries to justify everything Biden does. In fact, I have plenty to complain about.

For one thing, I think Biden has done too much deficit spending. The American Rescue Plan of 2021 had a lot of good stuff in it — for example, the expanded child tax credit — but it was fundamentally based on the mistaken idea that the country’s economic situation in 2021 was similar to its situation in 2020. The pandemic was still raging in 2021, but people had stopped hiding in their houses, and the economy was already recovering.

The CARES Act of 2020 was basically a bailout rather than a stimulus bill — the point was to make sure that people weren’t financially ruined during the time of social distancing. But because people were already spending again in 2021, the ARP acted more like a stimulus bill. It put a bunch of money in Americans’ pockets, and this time they went right out and spent it (along with some money that they had saved up from the CARES Act). That accelerated the recovery, but it also led to higher inflation. The U.S. was already suffering from supply chain disruptions, and then a brief oil price shock in 2022; the extra cash provided by the ARP poured a bit of fuel on that fire, contributing modestly to two years of declining real incomes for most Americans.

And some of the spending in the ARP consisted of health insurance subsidies, which is likely to push up prices in that industry without alleviating supply constraints or controlling costs.

Biden exacerbated all this with his student loan cancellation. This plan was extremely expensive, and will continue to be expensive going forward. It was not something we needed to do; instead, it was an attempt to win over the lefty youth, despite the fact that student loans aren’t a big priority for most young people and the lefty kids now hate Biden over Palestine anyway.

In general, Biden’s main domestic policy failing is that he’s too willing to throw subsidies at overpriced service industries, like health, education, child care, and so on, without any attempt to control costs in these industries. This is rooted in the new progressive consensus that “care jobs” represent the future of work, and that by subsidizing these industries, we can both make them cheaper for the average American and also create lots of jobs. But without measures to increase supply and improve efficiency, this pushes up prices. And in an era of high interest rates, it’s not clear the government can afford the extra debt.

In addition, Biden is a very old man. Although I think he seems more mentally acute than many people give him credit for — and more mentally acute than Trump, who is only three years younger and tends to ramble and fall asleep in court — age definitely does take a toll. This manifests in Biden occasionally saying foolish things and relying on outdated stereotypes, such as when he labeled key allies Japan and India “xenophobic”. Also, Biden’s age probably means less centralized leadership on economic policy.

So I am not a Biden shill. There is plenty that could be improved about his presidency, and the above is by no means an exhaustive list. But the positives strongly outweigh the negatives, so let’s talk about those.

Biden made industrial policy a reality

Throughout my entire life, I’ve heard Americans talk about the need to revive American manufacturing. First the Rust Belt and then the China Shock hollowed out the manufacturing workforce — employment plunged, and output stagnated. And yet neither Bush nor Obama seemed to have any plan for how to make it happen.

Trump talked a big game about bringing manufacturing back to America, but his signature initiative — the tariffs — didn’t make any headway in terms of reshoring. Trump’s attempt to harangue American companies into no longer shipping jobs overseas, and his bungled attempt to get Foxconn to build a factory in rural Wisconsin, were even less effective. There was no perceptible increase in factory construction, manufacturing output, or employment.

Then came Biden. With a pair of landmark bills — the (somewhat misnamed) Inflation Reduction Act and the bipartisan CHIPS and Science Act — he enacted America’s first real systematic manufacturing-oriented industrial policy since at least the early 1990s, and possibly since World War 2. A massive factory construction boom began almost immediately after the bills were signed:

Note that this graph is adjusted for the cost of new industrial building construction. So this isn’t a graph of inflation we’re looking at — this is a huge increase in actual construction. You can also see a big bump in construction employment in the nonresidential sector — despite the commercial real estate bust!

What kind of factories are being built? The new spending is mostly on chips and batteries:

So this is clearly a result of Biden’s two big bills. The U.S., which so often finds itself unable to build anything, is actually building something.

It’s still early days, of course. In fact, manufacturing output and employment haven’t risen yet! Building factories takes time. There are still many hurdles yet to overcome, and it’s a learning process. But finally, a President actually did something to restore U.S. manufacturing. After all those years of talk, someone did something, and that someone was Joe Biden.

The bigger question, of course, is: Was this the right thing to do? Plenty of people say that we shouldn’t be focusing on manufacturing at all — that we should simply step back and let the free market do its work, and that industrial policy is wasteful. We won’t know for a while whether they’re right. But what we do know is that China is ramping up its manufacturing machine to an incredible degree; in the face of that competition, we can either simply stop making anything in tradable manufactured goods and let our main rival do it all, while we specialize in agriculture and finance, or we can try to fight back.

“Fight back” is obviously the correct option. The usefulness of an economy is not measured purely in dollars of profit; an industrial economy is absolutely necessary in order to sustain a modern military that can keep us safe in the face of unprecedented external threats. Finance and agriculture cannot, by themselves, defend us against Chinese drones, missiles, and warships. Only manufacturing can do that. Semiconductors and batteries are incredibly crucial to defense manufacturing — chips are essential for every military device, especially precision weapons, and batteries power many of the drones that are taking over the battlefield. And of course, batteries are essential for fighting climate change, too.

In other words, Biden picked exactly the right industries to support. And our success or failure in supporting those industries will yield priceless insights for future efforts in other industries, like drones, ships, etc.

Meanwhile, the impact of this factory spending is widely distributed throughout the country — new battery factories are mostly in the South and Midwest, while a bunch of new chip factories are in Arizona, Texas, upstate New York, and the Mountain West. This means that industrial policy won’t just pour ever more investment into a few coastal “superstar” cities, as was the norm for the previous three decades.

This is the most consequential change in U.S. economic policy since Ronald Reagan. Trump may have been the one to smash the old free-trade laissez-faire consensus, but Biden is the first to start building something new in its place.

Biden is mostly good on foreign policy

In the memorable words of Xi Jinping, the world is facing “great changes unseen in a century”. The rise of China has changed absolutely everything. Suddenly, aggressive, authoritarian countries like Russia, Iran, and North Korea are no longer “rogue states” — they are members of an axis whose economic, industrial, and demographic heft rivals that of the U.S. and all of its allies combined.

In the face of that new axis, any U.S. President would struggle, but Biden has done extremely well given the circumstances.

First, he got the U.S. out of Afghanistan. Our forces had mostly been drawn down already under Obama, after the death of Bin Laden; Trump kept a skeleton force there and basically kicked the can down the road. Biden knew that being enmeshed in a “forever war” that had little hope of transforming Afghanistan into a stable country, much less a liberal democracy, was crippling the U.S.’ ability to respond to much more important threats. Therefore he did the right thing and withdrew. The withdrawal was executed well, with the only U.S. casualties being the 13 victims of an ISIS bombing. The only real blemish on the whole operation was the U.S.’ refusal to admit more Afghan translators and other collaborators as refugees.

With regards to China, Biden has done more than any other President — by far. Stupid gaffes notwithstanding, he has beefed up our alliances and quasi-alliances with India, Japan, the Philippines, and Australia, reinvigorating the Quad and creating AUKUS. The Philippines is allowing the U.S. to build bases on its soil for the first time in many years — bases that are very close to Taiwan and could help defend the island from invasion. Modi’s visit to the U.S. was an epochal moment in U.S.-India relations. Of course, much more needs to be done in order to forge a regional alliance capable of deterring China. But Biden has made important moves in the direction of that regional alliance, which neither Trump nor Obama did.

Biden has also dramatically strengthened U.S. export controls on the Chinese semiconductor industry. These won’t stop China’s progress, but they will slow it down and give America a fighting chance to preserve a world where the chips that tell American weapons where to strike aren’t all made in China. Export controls were a Trump innovation, but Biden has scaled them up to have real teeth.

It’s on Ukraine, though, that Biden did the best. Vladimir Putin’s decision to violate the norm against international conquest that had prevailed since World War 2 was a watershed moment — the end of the post-WW2 period and the beginning of a new era of great-power competition and instability. Had Russia been able to overrun Ukraine, it would now be menacing the rest of Europe. But because Joe Biden rushed a ton of weapons to Ukraine, the Ukrainians were able to defend their country, expel the Russians from about half of the territory they seized, and turn the war into the stalemate it is now. Russia’s casualties have been enormous — 450,000 dead and wounded, by the latest estimate, plus many thousands of armored vehicles destroyed.

Meanwhile, Biden’s sweeping sanctions and quick diplomacy ended up pushing Europe to unite more than it has…well, possibly ever. Sweden and Finland even joined NATO. Whereas Trump wanted to withdraw from NATO, and threatened to let Russia conquer allied countries, under Biden the alliance has become more vigorous, unified, and purposeful than it has been since the 1980s. Sweden and Norway even emerged from neutrality to join.

Thus, Russia, instead of conquering Ukraine and facing a divided, fractious Europe with its Soviet-era military hardware intact, now holds only a fifth of Ukraine and faces a united Europe, with much of its Soviet inheritance lying in ruins. That’s due to the valiance of the Ukrainian defenders and the financial aid of the Europeans, but Biden’s timely commitment of weapons played the decisive role. For that alone, Biden is the best foreign policy President since George H.W. Bush.

And U.S. support for Ukraine had another salutary effect — it was a wake-up call about the fact that the U.S. defense-industrial base has badly atrophied. The U.S. does not have the manufacturing capability to defend against China, but thanks to our Lend-Lease support for Ukraine, we now realize that we need to build it. And some efforts are actually happening ahead of schedule:

This isn’t nearly enough, of course. We need to build lots more missiles and ships, not just artillery shells, if we’re going to be able to deter China. But it’s a start, and it shows that the U.S. isn’t entirely still asleep about our military production deficiencies. Under Trump, we probably would still be asleep.

And then there’s the Gaza war. As I’ve said, I think Biden has been too conciliatory to Benjamin Netanyahu, and too reluctant to simply disengage from the Middle East and pivot to Asia. But that having been said, Biden has done a much better job than Trump would have done in terms of navigating a sensible middle path through the thorny conflict:

Of course the leftist kids give Biden no credit for this, but the leftist kids are silly.

Basically, on foreign policy, both ends of the horseshoe — the extremists of the MAGA Right and the “decolonial” Left — have united against Biden. That is a strong sign that he’s doing something right.

Biden has been a decent steward of the economy — and of public safety

Finally, we get to the bread-and-butter issues that affect most Americans’ daily lives. The economy is the thing many voters are still mad at Biden about — two years of real income declines will leave a bad taste in anyone’s mouth. And although some of the factors causing inflation were beyond Biden’s control, his spending probably did exacerbate the problem a bit, as I said before.

But Biden did a lot to help quell the inflation, too. First, and most importantly, he reappointed Jerome Powell as Fed chair. Many progressives had worried that Powell was too hawkish, and would cause a recession with too many interest rate hikes. But Biden stayed the course, and that turned out to be the right move. Powell’s rate hikes helped bring inflation down — not all the way to the 2% target, but enough so that real wages have started to grow again and are now on their pre-pandemic trend:

Source: Arin Dube

In fact, Biden did one other thing to help bring down inflation: He increased oil production. Although he came into office expecting to curb fracking in the name of the climate, the Ukraine war prompted an about-face. Biden opened up drilling, and the U.S. now produces more oil than any country ever has in the history of the world.

Cheaper oil doesn’t just make gasoline cheaper (although it does do that). It allows all kinds of businesses to move people and goods around more cheaply, allowing to produce things more cheaply — which lowers inflation.

So Biden did two big things to stop inflation — reappointed Powell, and ensured cheap, plentiful oil. Both of those were in the face of pressure from his own party, and showed a lot of courage and leadership. Less spending on health insurance and student debt would have taken a little of the edge off inflation in 2021, but Biden’s actions to bring down inflation in 2022 and 2023 outweigh the mistake.

Oh, and Biden’s administration also just casually stopped a banking crisis in its tracks back in early 2023. It was such a flawless victory that almost no one even remembers the panic!

Now the U.S. economy is humming on all cylinders. Wages are rising, growth is fast, productivity is growing, young people are doing better than their parents, wealth is up, employment is great, and so on. This Goldilocks situation won’t last forever, but it took some skillful macroeconomic management to get us here, and Biden — and the people in his administration — deserve some of the credit.

Another big thing Biden got right was crime. Violence surged under Donald Trump in 2020, and many feared that we might be seeing a repeat of the 1970s, when crime stayed sky-high for more than two decades. But under Biden, the murder rate has fallen dramatically:

Source: Axios

And the trend is continuing in 2024.

Does Biden get any of the credit for this? Well, yes, a bit. In 2020, many progressives were calling to defund the police; Biden fought against this idea from day 1. In fact, he has consistently supported hiring a lot more cops, together with various other measures to curb violence. And in fact, more cops have been hired; there are now more police working in America than ever before. Cops do help prevent crime — sorry, police abolitionists! — so Biden’s steadfast refusal to entertain notions of defunding the police probably gets a bit of the credit for the drop in crime.

So on the daily issues that affect Americans the most, Joe Biden has generally been an effective and responsible leader. And he has done this at the same time that he has strengthened U.S. alliances, halted Russia in its tracks, and begun a needed transformation of U.S. economic policy.

Not bad for an 81 year old, eh? It’s all about hiring good help. Anyway, given that record, I’m strongly inclined to keep Biden around for another 4 years. It’s not just that the alternative is so bad; Biden really has done a good job.


Subscribe now

Share

Read the whole story
mareino
20 hours ago
reply
Washington, District of Columbia
Share this story
Delete

People Don't Understand Affordability Requirements

1 Share

Shane Phillips, a researcher at UCLA Lewis Center for Regional Policy Studies, released a tool (using Terner Center at UC Berkeley’s data) that show the trade-off of mandating higher percentages of low-income housing against the production of market-rate housing in privately financed developments. As the percentage of inclusionary units increases in new developments, the number of market homes declines. Most importantly, once an inclusionary requirement reaches 20 - 25%, it ceases to produce additional low-income units and decreases the number of low-income homes built because the volume of market housing overall is less. A higher percentage does not mean the quantity, the real number of low-income homes, is higher. You’d be surprised how many in housing discourse are mathematically challenged by the concept of fractions.

Inclusionary zoning started in the early 1970s in California to encourage suburban communities to integrate by mandating a percentage of low-income housing in new rental developments. When President Nixon froze public housing construction, some urban communities innovated inclusionary zoning as a supplement. It became popular among progressive jurisdictions to make middle-class-oriented rental housing more low-income.

Within ten years of implementation, pundits, researchers and its many original sponsors conceded it didn’t build much low-income housing. Here’s Donald Terner, Housing Director under Jerry Brown and one of Inclusionary Zoning’s original sponsors explaining it’s primary problem upon roll-out.

Local government offers the developer incentives to make [affordability requirements] economically feasible, says Terner. Without greater density, government loans, land write downs or parking regulation waivers, inclusionary zoning was "well-intended nonsense."

— SF Examiner, 2/9/1986

An excerpt from a book on the East Bay Area’s left-wing economic revolution in the 1970s explains how the socialists in Berkeley who introduced one of California’s first ordinances knew their 25% inclusionary requirements weren't feasible.

The requirement that low-to-moderate income housing be provided in any development was included to guarantee that new development would not be exclusively for wealthy residents. But proponents also understood that no private, speculative developer would either desire to provide lower priced housing, or be able to afford such inclusions without subsidies.

Inclusionary zoning is, as Donald Terner said, a well-intended tool sometimes weaponized by exclusionary communities or proponents to act as unofficial housing moratoriums, with voters often none the wiser. Most people when asked what percentage of new developments should be low-income have no idea of the financial feasibility or where funding is coming from, so whoever says the highest number wins.

That’s how you get results like Portland’s, where a 20% inclusionary policy that promised 555 low-rent homes a year resulted in only 189 a year. In 2016, San Francisco voters passed a nice sounding 25% affordability requirement. The Controller’s Office predicted it would create fewer low income homes, but many politicians and activists dismissed this as neoliberal fearmongering. Like clockwork, the city had a 75% reduction in low income housing funding because the revenue they get from housing construction tanked just two years later. Finally admitting it didn’t work, the Board of Supervisors had to reverse this policy last year as homelessness skyrocketted and construction was completely unfeasible. A painful lesson in mathematics that making percentages higher does not inherently make the quantity higher.

While San Francisco’s case was unintended by voters, some exclusionary communities intentionally abuse inclusionary zoning knowing exactly what they’re doing. Atherton, the wealthy Silicon Valley suburb, mandated 25% inclusionary as a way to subvert state law forcing them to build homes. Republican-run Huntington Beach has announced its intent to do the same. 

Let's be honest: there’s nowhere in the United States or any city on Earth where unfunded mandates for subsidized housing in new developments produce a lot of low-income housing. Most places with high inclusionary rates are among the most unaffordable cities in the world and produce the fewest homes.

Inclusionary zoning higher than 5% or even 10% is only feasible or profitable in very expensive markets. San Francisco’s own Planning Department found that with high inclusionary requirements, the only place building housing will not be a net-negative in revenue is in the highest of high rent neighborhoods, only. Rents are set by the market, translated from what enough people are willing to pay, and market rents must provide enough revenue to exceed the cost of construction, debt service and profit margin.

Anything approaching 20% inclusionary housing mandates mostly materialize in places where projects are profitable enough to subsidize those inclusionary units, and those projects are usually expensive luxury housing. That’s why most of the yield from inclusionary zoning is coming from places like downtown Los Angeles or San Francisco rather than middle class areas. The latter’s rents aren’t high enough to cross-subsidize 1/5th of the homes.

For example, San Francisco’s real estate is dealing with two events: one is high-interest rates meant to deter so-called over-construction, and the second is the outmigration of higher-income professionals from the city. There are enough luxury condos and high-end rentals in downtown S.F. relative to demand, so building went from being small to almost nothing. While middle-class developers can build in cheaper places like Texas or Arizona, only high-end, luxury developers can afford the cost of construction in San Francisco and much of California. When the median new home in San Francisco costs well over $1 million per unit to build, thanks to high material costs, high-interest rates, and an expensive approval process, you cannot price a home any lower than that.

We should look towards Vienna, Austria for how we want to approach integrated housing development. American puff pieces about Vienna never engage with the substance or specifics of how Vienna achieves low-income housing ratios as high as 40% in new developments. Chiefly, it’s not an unfunded neoliberal mandate expecting developers to provide public goods by incentive. Vienna builds social housing via a 1% income tax towards a dedicated housing fund. The municipal agencies then incentivize competition among client developers with these funds. This is also why development looks better in Vienna than in most American cities (that and building regulations are modern and more evidence-based). Whereas inclusionary zoning essentially taxes new housing to pay for subsidized units, Vienna taxes the city’s wealth to pay private developers with loans and land leasing in exchange for high-quality, social housing on the city’s terms.

The unfunded mandates version of inclusionary zoning we practice in expensive U.S. cities doesn’t work at producing sizable amounts of low-income housing, and we knew that within years of its creation. It was a neoliberal solution to dwindling HUD investment of public housing and unsuccessful integration. It’s as silly as mandating grocery stores sell 20% of their food below market prices to solve food insecurity or 20% of gas stations to sell below market fuel to solve transportation. The debate should be on whether to subsidize the market producers, create public goods or subsidize people in need.

I don’t believe inclusionary zoning is bad. Once we acknowledge that subsidized housing requires subsidies and taxing new housing is sub-optimal over taxing income or land, which are the actual instruments of high rents and home prices, we can start to realize some solutions. Realistically, unfunded inclusionary zoning requirements should not exceed 10% of total projects and should be traded for swift approvals, greater density and fee exemptions. Our most successful inclusionary programs are density bonuses, so let’s build off that. In the 1990s, some California cities — including progressive Berkeley — approached inclusionary zoning by offering loans to developers that they would pay back with realized rents. Smart!

Inclusionary zoning is not an affordability policy, it's an integration policy that is constantly misused. Unfunded mandates can’t replace the hard work of taxing monied interests — chiefly landowners and wealthy residents, which includes all real estate holders as well as developers — to pay for public goods. Cities wrongly depend disproportionately on the borrowed capital of multifamily developers, not even house flippers or single-family developers, to subsidize housing. Rents and home prices derive not from who builds housing but who owns housing and land under it. We should subsidize our low-income housing by taxing landowners and the high incomes inflating housing costs, not tax what we lack, which is housing.

Subscribe to The Discourse Lounge

I analyze housing affordability, transportation, culture and urban living. Among other things.

Read the whole story
mareino
2 days ago
reply
Washington, District of Columbia
Share this story
Delete

Stop making people do the wrong jobs

1 Share

NextCity recently published a hot take by Steffen Berr tying the ways in which the US is failing at reducing pedestrian deaths to the misaligned training that most transportation engineers in the US receive. Berr explains that a transportation engineer “is a really a civil engineer who has received a little exposure to the transportation sector.” Due to the structure of accredited degree programs, “In a best-case scenario, a civil engineer will only take three transportation classes during their bachelor’s degree. In the worst case, they’ll only take one: Introduction to Highway Engineering. To put this into perspective, the most educated professionals we entrust to design and run our roads and streets have received only half of a minor with a handful of credits on the topic.”

Berr goes on to address the reasonable objection that in many fields, people learn on the job. But what transportation engineers learn on the job, per Berr, is not things like how to choose the most appropriate intersection for the desired use, how the road system should be laid out at a network/route level, or how to fix congestion (none of which, he argues, they learn in school either.) Instead, they learn “how to navigate the impressive amounts of bureaucracy that have been built up in the industry, memorize an impressive vocabulary of technical jargon, practice with design software like AutoCAD to produce engineering plans, and how to copy the current engineering standards. There is no exposure to deep levels of theory that can help our future professionals create original solutions to fundamental problems like safety, congestion, emissions and ethics.” 

I’m less interested in Berr’s point about the wrong degree requirements than I am in his observation about what the job of transportation engineer actually is. As Stafford Beer observed, “the purpose of a system is what it does,” and by analogy, the purpose of a job is not its stated goals but what the people who do it actually do day to day.1 When talking to people who’ve never worked in government, the biggest disconnect is usually a lack of understanding of the actual jobs of public servants. A rather dramatic illustration of this comes from a Mercatus Center podcast with Lant Pritchett in which he shares an anecdote about advocating for evidence-based policy in the Indian bureaucracy. 

After they had done the RCT [randomized control trial] showing that this Balsakhi program of putting tutors in the schools really led to substantial gains and learning achievement and reading outcomes, he took it to the secretary of education of the place in which they had done the RCT. And he said, “Oh, by the way, I have the solution to your problem of low learning levels, or at least part of the solution. Look, we’ve got this powerful evidence that this works to improve leading outcomes by putting these volunteer tutors and pulling their low learning kids out.”

The response of the secretary of education was, “What do you think my job is? Why do you think that this is a solution to a problem I have? Look around my office. See these piles and piles of files that keep me busy 60 hours a week and not one of these files is about a child not learning. I’m under no pressure about that problem. If I try and transfer a teacher, I’ve got a court case on my hand. If I try and close a school, I got a court case on my hand. My job is to administer the existing education policy such that there’s policy compliance. Super kudos to you for this cute little study you’ve done. It has nothing to do with my job as secretary of education.”

Ouch. And that’s a secretary of an agency serving a county with 1.5 billion people. 

I suspect a lot of public servants in the US will read that and think “My job is not quite as bad as that but it sure feels that way a lot.” The people I know maintain enough connection to the actual mission to avoid such a meltdown (though I find the secretary’s frankness refreshing.) But both these stories help explain a conundrum that many who care about effective government (or, shall we say, state capacity) struggle to explain: the contradiction between the dedication, smarts, and creativity of most public servants and the sometimes terrible outcomes they are associated with, like the recent tragic lapses in administering student loans by the US Department of Education. (Or in Berr’s world, the 40,000 traffic deaths we’re stuck with every year while countries like the Netherlands have dropped their own already low number by 46%.2) To be sure, there are often extraordinary outcomes (hello Direct File!), and we notice them far less often, to our own detriment. But while it’s impossible to give government a meaningful overall grade, if its job is to meet challenges we face (national security, climate change, an effective safety net, etc.), we are at risk of falling dangerously short. The problem isn’t that public servants are doing a bad job, it’s that they’re doing a great job — at the wrong jobs.

The (unnamed in this context) Indian Secretary of Education seems to agree: “My job is to administer the existing education policy such that there’s policy compliance.” I highly doubt that’s the job he thought he was getting, or the job he wanted to do. Berr is on the same general theme when he says that what transportation engineers learn on the job is “how to operate in the industry effectively as it has been currently set up.” Note his use of the word effectively. Effective towards what? Not towards reducing traffic deaths or congestion levels. “All the experience in the world of copying and pasting a standard invented fifty years ago is useless when the problems that the standard was invented to resolve have changed,” he says. “Understanding this sheds a lot of light as to why 40,000 people are still dying on our roads every year and why your local city insists on laying down sharrows [which are known to be ineffective and often dangerous] in their latest round of “safety improvements.” Quite frankly, it’s because we have no idea what we are doing.”

This is a useful nuance as I develop a framework for building state capacity. One of my admittedly obvious and oversimplified tenets is that systems have both “go energy” and “stop energy,” much as a car has a gas pedal and a brake. You wouldn’t drive a car without a brake, but you also wouldn’t drive a car in which the brake was pressed all the time, even when you were trying to accelerate. This is a good metaphor for how we’re dealing with the implementation of CHIPS, IRA, and the Infrastructure Bill, for example, where the clear intent is speed and scale but the public servants responsible are held back from that by the brakes of overly zealous compliance functions. I hear a version of this at every agency I visit: “Congress tells us to do something. Then the compliance offices keep us from doing that very thing.” (And side note for further discussion: This is an issue of representation, voice, and democracy.) The stop energy in our government is currently a lot bigger than it should be. We’re hitting the gas but we’re not accelerating because we’re pressing the brake at the same time. 

Lots of people in government have “stop energy” jobs. We need them, and we need them to be good at them. I don’t want to live in a country where our government doesn’t exercise “stop authority.” I try to remember not to complain when my flight is delayed because I really don’t want to die in a plane crash, and a rigidly implemented checklist is a big part of how we keep safe (the current epidemic of doors and engine cowlings blowing off notwithstanding). I also really like being pretty confident that a pill I’m taking has been tested and not tampered with. I like thinking our nuclear arsenal is protected. You know, little things like that.

Stop energy is critical. Rigid adherence to protocol is usually lifesaving. But it must exist in balance. I recently learned the Navy concept of “front of sub/back of sub.” The back of a nuclear submarine, where the nukes live, is run by the book. You don’t deviate from the checklist. You don’t innovate. You don’t question. The front of the sub, on the other hand, is responsible for navigating through dark waters. You have to improvise. You have to make judgment calls. There are manuals and checklists, for sure, but the nature of the work calls for a different approach, and the Navy recognizes that the cultures of front and back have evolved appropriately to meet distinct needs. 

There are times, of course, when you’ll need front of sub judgment in a back of sub context. If the plane I was on was about to be bombed by an enemy combatant (unlikely in my life, I hope), I would be okay with the pilot using her discretion to cut a corner or two on the takeoff checklist, because the very thing that checklist is there to protect (the lives of the people on board) would under threat from a different vector. Taking every precaution in that scenario could be reckless. That’s a bit how I feel about the NEPA reviews and other bureaucratic processes that are holding back building the infrastructure we need to move to a low-carbon economy. I wish for the public servants in charge to see the threat of inaction – those species the checklist is trying to protect are threatened by temperature rise as much or more than they are by the project in question – and make good judgment calls about getting the plane off the runway a lot quicker, so to speak. This feels like a domain where back of sub culture has more hold than it should given the circumstances. And to Berr’s point, we can’t rely on back of sub culture when the checklist and protocols it uses no longer serve the purpose.

Of course, “stop energy” roles can themselves be balanced – if only I had a dime for every discussion about the value of lawyers who get to yes and the frustrations with those who seem to do nothing but block. The analogy breaks down a bit here because the items on a pre-flight checklist are binary – they are either red or green – whereas the ad hoc checklists that lawyers assemble to ensure compliance before signing off on an action are almost always shades of gray – they can be open to lots of interpretations. Any given lawyer, or compliance officer, or ethics cop can treat their role with appropriate balance, reserving their stop authority only when the risks truly outweigh the benefits. But getting the culture of a team, department, or agency to balance stop and go correctly at a macro level is extremely difficult. It’s rare to see leadership really change that balance, or for it to stick. It’s a retail approach, hugely dependent on personalities and circumstances.

What would a wholesale approach to getting back into balance look like? One answer should be a simple matter of top-down workforce planning, of the kind our Office of Personnel Management should be empowered to do: fewer stop energy jobs relative to go energy jobs. Hire more doers than brakers, both in how the position is defined and in the characteristics of the people selected for the job. But that proposal needs several important caveats. Of course, every great employee is some mix of these energies – a “go only” employee would be exhausting and dangerous in all but the most extreme circumstances – so we’re talking about a general orientation. More importantly, having fewer brakers will only result in enormous backlogs if they have the same stopping power. But there are plenty of functions where its possible to safely move from default no to default yes, possibly with an after the fact correction mechanism.3 Instead of requiring form redesigns to go through a long White House approval process before they can be made available to the public, for instance, allow agencies to apply the appropriate level of scrutiny and sign-off for the form at hand and develop a process for catching and quickly fixing anything determined to be detrimental. This example speaks to the issue of multiple levels of safeguards. Loosening a safeguard that operates at the top level of federal government may not make much difference to overall stop energy if agencies, or in turn their subcomponents, or even teams, react by strengthening their own safeguard processes. There might be something like a Law of Conservation of Safeguards at play here. But it’s still worth considering the value of moving to default yes processes where appropriate. 

Share Eating Policy

Of course, the question of the nature of the job public servants are tasked with is about much more than just stop vs go. It’s about what kind of work we’ve decided to invest in. I go into some depth about this in Chapter 5 of Recoding America as it relates to our lack of investment in digital competencies and how ideologies about private sector superiority led to a big outsourcing push just as digital was beginning to massively transform society.

…these internal competencies in digital became necessary just as we were jettisoning internal competencies of all sorts, not developing them. Instead of digital competency, government has developed extensive processes and procedures for procurement of digital work, and the ins and outs of procurements sometimes seem more complex and technical than the latest programming languages.

This points to another way to understand the disconnect between high employee performance and the outcomes our government produces (or fails to), especially relative to the investment made.4 Take procurement. I know a lot of people in procurement who are really good at their jobs. Some of them are considered really good because they’re great at the “back of sub” tasks of making sure every box is checked, and a manager might feel compelled to give them a high performance rating because of their thoroughness and dedication, even if the people who need the thing being acquired are frustrated by the slowness and rigidity of the process, and even if the thing that is ultimately acquired has checked all the boxes but doesn’t actually work. (For an example of this, see Chapter 4 of Recoding America.) But many of these procurement professionals operate according to “front of sub” principles, and are enormously creative and mission-driven. The other public servants who rely on them to procure things value them enormously. They may or may not receive high ratings, if the manager is judging them based on a “back of sub” approach. But procurement processes simply should not be as complex and burdensome as they have become. Both of these kinds of procurement professionals are doing a job that simply shouldn’t exist in its current form.

Especially with the looming threat of the return of Schedule F under a possible Trump administration, there’s a lot of talk of public sector employee performance and protections. I agree strongly with Donald Kettl, who has said about the left’s silence on civil service reforms in the face of Schedule F: “You can’t fight something with nothing.” I hope to be part of proposing a something there, something that improves government’s ability to fill many open positions and to effectively and ethically manage the workforce. But we could succeed entirely at that and still fail to meet the challenges in front of us if the jobs we fill are the wrong jobs.

Another of my admittedly obvious and oversimplified principles of how to build state capacity is that there are really only three things you can do:

  • You can have more of the right people

  • You can focus them on the right things

  • You can burden them less.

There is obviously quite a lot to say about each of those things, and they are all deeply intertwined. A big reason we don’t have more of the right people is that we overburden both the people responsible for hiring and the applicants, focusing both on the wrong things. We overburden public servants generally because we have designed too many of their jobs to stop bad things instead of to enable the things we desperately need. We are too often asking if public servants are doing a good job instead of understanding and questioning the nature of the jobs they’ve been hired to do. 

We need a much more robust understanding of how to fix the problem of hiring the right people to do the wrong jobs. We need wholesale strategies for tuning the dial between front of sub and back of sub, between stop and go, between brake and gas, and refocusing the job of public servants on the work that’s most directly meaningful towards the outcomes we want. We need staffers in agencies who act as if the climate crisis is the enemy plane that’s about to bomb us. We need transportation engineers whose actual job – as practiced on a daily basis, at scale – is to reduce congestion and pollution and improve and save lives. We need Secretaries of Education who have time in their day to look at the study on improving learning achievement, and maybe even take action on it. We need all of this now.

Imagine a world in which this — not just enforcing rules, not even just helping agencies fill open jobs, but ensuring that federal government fills the right jobs — was the mandate of an empowered and deeply collaborative Office of Personnel Management. They couldn’t do it alone, of course — it’s agencies that define the jobs they think they need and Congress that throws down law after law they must comply with, feeding the need for compliance. The White House Office of Management and Budget adds its own reporting and compliance burdens. Each would need to buy in on an agenda of building state capacity and do their part. But this is what workforce planning should really be, and in 2025, we will need it more than ever. If Biden gets a second term, this is the kind of ambitious agenda he should set.

Share

Subscribe to Eating Policy

In business, culture eats strategy. In government, culture eats policy. Here we'll talk about the problems of state capacity (government's ability to achieve its policy goals) and how to fix them. From the author of Recoding America.

Read the whole story
mareino
2 days ago
reply
Washington, District of Columbia
Share this story
Delete

EPA issues four rules limiting pollution from fossil fuel power plants | Ars Technica

2 Shares

Today, the US Environmental Protection Agency announced a suite of rules that target pollution from fossil fuel power plants. In addition to limits on carbon emissions and a tightening of existing regulations on mercury releases, additional rules target coal ash waste left over from power generation and contaminants in the water used during the operation of power plants. While some of these regulations will affect the operation of plants powered by natural gas, most directly target the use of coal and will likely be the final nail in the coffin for the already dying industry.

The decision to release all four rules at the same time goes beyond simply getting the pain over with at once. Rules governing carbon emissions are expected to influence the emissions of other pollutants like mercury, and vice versa. As a result, the EPA expects that creating a single plan for compliance with all the rules will be more cost-effective.

Targeting carbon

The regulations that target carbon dioxide emissions have been in the works for roughly a year. The rules came in response to a Supreme Court decision in West Virginia v. EPA, which ruled that Clean Air Act regulations had to target individual power plants rather than giving states flexibility regarding how to meet broader standards. As a result, the new rules target carbon dioxide the only way they can: Plants can either switch to burning non-fossil fuels such as green hydrogen, or they can capture their carbon emissions.

The EPA did recognize, however, that the decline of coal was handling some of the issue on its own. No new plants have been built in years, and most of the existing ones are growing increasingly old and expensive compared to cheap natural gas and renewables, leading to widespread closures. So the EPA set up tiers of rules based on how long plants were expected to be operating. If a coal plant would be shut within a decade or two anyway, it could simply continue operating as it had or meet less stringent requirements.

In the final rule, this has been simplified down into three categories. Any plant that will cease operations before 2032 will get an exemption. Those that will shut prior to 2039 will have to meet less stringent requirements, equivalent to replacing 40 percent of their fuel with natural gas. Anything operating past 2039 will have to eliminate 90 percent of its carbon emissions.

Natural gas plants will face similar tiers of stringency, but this time based on how often they're in use. Plants that operate at less than 20 percent of their capacity, such as those that simply fill in during periods of low renewable energy production, can meet regulations simply by adopting low-emissions fuel. Those that run between 20 and 40 percent of the time have to meet operational efficiency standards, while anything that's operational over 40 percent of the time will have to eliminate 90 percent of its emissions.

Additional changes will allow plants some temporary exemptions from regulations if they're deemed critical to maintaining grid stability.

Should the rules survive court challenges, it's unlikely that more than a handful of coal plants will continue operations. Since burning coal produces a large range of pollutants, this will provide substantial non-climate benefits. The EPA estimates that in two decades, there will be significant declines in nitrogen oxide and sulfur dioxide pollution, fewer particulates, and less mercury released to the environment. Over the intervening years, this will avoid 1,200 premature deaths, nearly 360,000 asthma problems, and roughly 50,000 lost work days. All of that leads to substantial economic benefits, as seen in this chart.

Thanks to tax incentives for carbon capture contained in the Inflation Reduction Act and the continuing fall in the price of renewables, the EPA estimates that meeting the standards will result in a "negligible impact on electricity prices."


Page 2

Limitations on mercury have existed for some time, and the EPA has been working on tightening those rules since shortly after Biden entered office. The rule being announced today targets the burning of lignite, a softer form of coal that burns inefficiently due to a high level of contaminants. Lignite-fired plants will see existing limits on mercury emissions drop by 70 percent; all coal plants will see limits on other toxic metals fall by 67 percent. Plants will also be required to install real-time monitoring systems and make their data available to the public.

Overall, this will cut mercury, arsenic, and lead emissions, with obvious benefits for public health; the EPA expects to see a lower risk of fatal heart attacks, cancer, and developmental delays in children. As an added benefit, compliance will also cut carbon emissions.

Separately, coal plants will see tighter regulations on the discharge of water. Water is used to move the material left behind when coal is burned, termed "fly ash," out of the combustion area and into longer-term storage. It's also used in the machinery that removes pollutants (including mercury and sulfur) from the exhaust gasses of coal plants. During these processes, the water frequently picks up the toxic contaminants that are associated with coal use.

The EPA is also tightening the limits of contaminants allowed in this water before it is returned to the environment. Again, coal-fired plants that will be closed within the next decade will be allowed to continue operating under present restrictions until their closing; only those kept open for longer will need to meet the new requirements. "Following rigorous analysis, EPA has determined that this final rule will have minimal effects on electricity prices," the agency says. "EPA’s analysis shows that the final rule will provide billions of dollars in health and environmental benefits each year."

The final rule being announced today is largely closing a loophole in the existing rules regarding fly ash, which contains lots of toxic metals that can leach into the groundwater near storage facilities. Existing rules regulate many of the storage areas, but the agency has identified a number of inactive disposal sites at active coal plants, a situation that fell outside existing regulations. (Existing regulations targeted active disposal sites at operating plants and inactive sites at shuttered facilities.) The new rule brings these exceptions into the same regulatory scheme that governs the rest of the storage sites.

Sending signals

As noted above, the EPA argues that tying these regulations together will help those running coal-fired plants sort out how to meet them. "EPA is providing a predictable regulatory outlook for power companies, including opportunities to reduce compliance complexity, and clear signals to create market and price stability," the agency says.

Given that all four of these regulations target coal-burning plants, those "clear signals" are that coal is going away. It was doing so on its own, but the added regulations narrow the opportunities for coal plants to operate profitably.

Given the outsize impacts of coal pollution on public health, this also makes the EPA's economic case much easier. The vast costs of the health impacts will always dwarf the costs of compliance, especially in this case, where many plants will close for economic reasons before they even need to worry about compliance.

But the real battle will come in maintaining the rules governing carbon emissions in natural gas plants through court challenges and changes in administration. Natural gas is economically competitive, and it is currently playing key roles in both eliminating coal from the grid and balancing out the intermittent production from renewables. But long-term, our climate goals require that its emissions go away as well.

Given that these rules may not survive elections and the courts, it's not clear that the EPA's announcement is as direct a signal as our climate needs it to be.

Read the whole story
mareino
5 days ago
reply
Washington, District of Columbia
acdha
10 days ago
reply
Washington, DC
Share this story
Delete
Next Page of Stories